Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (6.4 MB, 432 trang )
140
Trade Finance during the Great Trade Collapse
second quarter of 2009. The mean sectoral decline is 25.3 percent for imports
and 20.9 percent for exports. There is considerable heterogeneity across sectors; some sectors even saw an expansion of trade, while others experienced a
large contraction. Thus, a great deal of cross-sectoral variation could potentially be exploited.
Estimation Results
Regarding the results of the regression analysis, table 7.2 presents the results when
the dependent variable is U.S. imports by sector, and table 7.3 presents the results
when the dependent variable is U.S. exports.
Throughout, the tables report the standardized beta coefficients, obtained by
first renormalizing each variable to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation
of 1. Thus, all the regression coefficients correspond to the number of standard
deviations’ change in the left-hand side variable that would be due to a 1 standard
deviation change in the right-hand side variable. This also implies that the magnitudes of the coefficients are comparable across variables that may have very different scales when not normalized.
The controls for sector size in trade and labor intensity come in as strongly significant across the board. In addition, the main two variables found to be significant in Levchenko, Lewis, and Tesar (2010)—durability and vertical production
linkages—remain strongly significant, with all p-values less than 1 percent in the
case of U.S. imports.
The coefficients on the financial variables are less consistent. Columns (1)
and (2) of each table report the results for the trade credit variables (accounts
payable and accounts receivable). For imports, the coefficients are not significant, and the point estimates are close to zero. For exports, accounts payable is
not significant with a near-zero point estimate, while the accounts receivable
variable is significant at the 10 percent level, but with the “wrong” sign: exports
in sectors that extend trade credit more intensively fell by less.
Columns (3) and (4) of tables 7.2 and 7.3 report the results for the measures of
external finance dependence and asset tangibility. Although for both directions of
trade flows, the Rajan and Zingales (1998) measure of external dependence is
insignificant with a near-zero beta coefficient, asset tangibility is significant, but
once again with the “wrong” sign: sectors with a greater share of tangible assets
should have a relatively easier time getting credit during a crunch; those sectors
also had larger falls in both imports and exports.
Column (5) reports the results for the trade-weighted credit contraction in the
partner countries. Once again, while the coefficient is nearly zero for U.S. imports,
for exports it is significant at 10 percent with the “wrong” sign: exports from the
141
Durable dummy
Share of intrafirm importsa
Average time to ship
Share shipped by vessel
Share shipped by truck and
pipeline
Average distance shipped
TWCC
Asset tangibility
External finance dependence
Accounts receivable/sales
Accounts payable/cost of
goods sold
Dependent variable change
in imports (%)
–0.206***
(0.059)
0.076
(0.085)
(1)
–0.215***
(0.054)
0.056
(0.071)
(2)
–0.194***
(0.048)
0.035
(0.041)
(3)
Table 7.2 U.S. Imports and Financial Variables, Q2 2008–Q2 2009
–0.258***
(0.046)
–0.185***
(0.071)
(4)
–0.185***
(0.050)
–0.008
(0.069)
(5)
–0.193***
(0.047)
0.087
(0.063)
(6)
–0.212***
(0.047)
–0.133**
(0.067)
–0.148**
(0.063)
(7)
0.022
(0.049)
–0.191***
(0.049)
(9)
(continued next page)
–0.220***
(0.046)
–0.123**
(0.058)
(8)
142
b
(2)
–0.195***
(0.044)
–0.073*
(0.038)
–0.073
(0.061)
–0.129**
(0.054)
415
0.122
(1)
–0.200***
(0.042)
–0.092*
(0.047)
–0.076
(0.061)
–0.113**
(0.054)
415
0.124
(4)
–0.154***
(0.047)
–0.027
(0.042)
–0.064
(0.058)
–0.135**
(0.054)
432
0.138
(3)
–0.203***
(0.043)
–0.069*
(0.039)
–0.08
(0.062)
–0.126**
(0.055)
423
0.124
–0.192***
(0.040)
–0.064*
(0.037)
–0.078
(0.061)
–0.122**
(0.051)
435
0.116
(5)
–0.178***
(0.045)
–0.071**
(0.035)
–0.075
(0.059)
–0.121**
(0.058)
436
0.114
(6)
–0.172***
(0.043)
–0.074**
(0.031)
–0.07
(0.061)
–0.114**
(0.055)
436
0.119
(7)
–0.197***
(0.041)
–0.074**
(0.034)
–0.068
(0.062)
–0.124**
(0.052)
434
0.133
(8)
–0.205***
(0.046)
–0.061
(0.037)
–0.078
(0.060)
–0.110**
(0.053)
437
0.112
(9)
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Note: Standardized beta coefficients reported throughout. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the percentage reduction in U.S. imports in a sixdigit NAICS category from Q2 2008 to Q2 2009 (year-to-year). The financial variables are described in detail in the text.
a. “Share of intrafirm imports” is total U.S. imports, computed from U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis multinationals data and averaged over the period 2002–06.
b. “Average downstream use” is the average use output in a sector as an intermediate input in other sectors.
c. “Share in total” is the share of a sector in total U.S. imports.
d. “Elasticity of substitution” between varieties in a sector is sourced from Broda and Weinstein (2006).
e. “Labor intensity” is the compensation of employees as a share of value added, from the U.S. 2002 Benchmark Input-Output Table (BEA 2002).
* significant at 10 percent.
** significant at 5 percent.
*** significant at 1 percent.
Observations
R-squared
Labor intensitye
Elasticity of substitutiond
Share in totalc
Average downstream use
Table 7.2 continued
143
Durable dummy
Share of intrafirm importsa
Average time to ship
Share shipped by vessel
Share shipped by truck
and pipeline
Average distance shipped
TWCC
Asset tangibility
External finance dependence
Accounts receivable/sales
Accounts payable/cost of
goods sold
Dependent variable change
in imports (%)
–0.094
(0.058)
0.012
(0.068)
(1)
–0.137**
(0.055)
0.105*
(0.063)
(2)
–0.100**
(0.050)
0.01
(0.050)
(3)
Table 7.3 U.S. Exports and Financial Variables, Q2 2008–Q2 2009
–0.152***
(0.054)
–0.156**
(0.062)
(4)
–0.082
(0.051)
0.120*
(0.065)
(5)
–0.111**
(0.050)
0.093
(0.064)
(6)
–0.125**
(0.052)
–0.093
(0.062)
–0.083
(0.070)
(7)
0.016
(0.050)
–0.106**
(0.050)
(9)
(continued next page)
–0.104**
(0.050)
–0.042
(0.056)
(8)
144
(1)
–0.098**
(0.042)
–0.191***
(0.067)
–0.049
(0.087)
–0.135**
(0.054)
415
0.097
(2)
–0.090**
(0.043)
–0.194***
(0.064)
–0.042
(0.085)
–0.134***
(0.050)
415
0.106
(3)
–0.100**
(0.043)
–0.189***
(0.067)
–0.049
(0.087)
–0.129**
(0.050)
423
0.098
(4)
–0.054
(0.048)
–0.199***
(0.062)
–0.036
(0.082)
–0.156***
(0.052)
432
0.116
(5)
–0.091**
(0.041)
–0.196***
(0.064)
–0.05
(0.079)
–0.133***
(0.050)
437
0.117
(6)
–0.073*
(0.044)
–0.210***
(0.068)
–0.062
(0.079)
–0.145***
(0.050)
436
0.113
(7)
–0.07
(0.044)
–0.208***
(0.061)
–0.049
(0.081)
–0.156***
(0.050)
436
0.112
(8)
–0.095**
(0.041)
–0.190***
(0.065)
–0.045
(0.083)
–0.143***
(0.050)
436
0.105
(9)
–0.098**
(0.041)
–0.188***
(0.064)
–0.05
(0.083)
–0.145***
(0.050)
437
0.104
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Notes: Standardized beta coefficients reported throughout. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the percentage reduction in U.S. exports in a sixdigit NAICS category from Q2 2008 to Q2 2009 (year-to-year). The financial variables are described in detail in the text.
a. “Share of intrafirm imports” is total U.S. imports, computed from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis multinationals data and averaged over the period 2002–06.
b. “Average downstream use” is the average use output in a sector as an intermediate input in other sectors.
c. “Share in total” is the share of a sector in total U.S. imports.
d. “Elasticity of substitution” between varieties in a sector is sourced from Broda and Weinstein (2006).
e. “Labor intensity” is the compensation of employees as a share of value added, from the U.S. 2002 Benchmark Input-Output Table (BEA 2002).
* significant at 10 percent.
** significant at 5 percent.
*** significant at 1 percent.
Observations
R-squared
Labor intensitye
Elasticity of substitutiond
Share in totalc
Average downstream useb
Table 7.3 continued
The Role of Trade Finance in the U.S. Trade Collapse: A Skeptic’s View
145
United States fell by less in sectors dominated by trading partners with greater
credit contractions.
Columns (6), (7), and (8) report the results of using shipping lags measures
(average distance shipped, share shipped by truck and pipeline, share shipped by
vessel, and average time to ship). For U.S. exports, these do not seem to matter. For
imports, there is some evidence for the role of shipping lags. Although the simple
average distance shipped is not significant (column [6]), the mode of transportation is. Sectors with higher shares of imports shipped by ocean and other means
(usually truck and pipeline) experienced larger falls than sectors with higher
shares of air shipping (column [7]). Furthermore, sectors with longer shipping
times (column [8]) had larger falls in imports. The magnitudes of the beta coefficients are also economically significant: a 1.0 standard deviation change in share
shipped by ocean is associated with a 0.148 standard deviations’ greater fall in
imports. Similarly, a 1.0 standard deviation change in shipping time leads imports
to fall by 0.123 standard deviations.
One difficulty in interpreting the shipment coefficients is that the mode of
shipping could be an endogenous variable. For instance, firms choose the shipping mode optimally in response to demand volatility (Hummels and Schaur
2010). A second problem is that the mode of shipping is likely to be correlated
with the type of goods (for example, automobiles account for a substantial fraction of the decline in trade and are never shipped by air). Although other industry
characteristics that are explicitly controlled for may sweep out some of this variation, others could be missing from the analysis.
Finally, column (9) reports the results of regressing imports and exports on the
share of intrafirm trade in the sector; although the coefficient has the “right” sign,
it is very close to zero and insignificant.
Conclusions
It is widely recognized that the current global downturn was triggered by a
large-scale financial crisis. At the same time, the world experienced a collapse in
international trade of a magnitude unseen since World War II. If one puts the
two events together, it is a reasonable hypothesis that financial factors contributed to the collapse in trade. However, hard evidence for this has proven elusive. This chapter tests a battery of hypotheses concerning how financial factors
could have affected U.S. imports and exports at the sector level. Overall, the
results show little evidence that financial factors contributed to the trade collapse. This finding is in sharp contrast to the other measures that were found, in
earlier studies, to matter a great deal: vertical production linkages and the role
of durables.
146
Trade Finance during the Great Trade Collapse
The remainder of this section highlights some boundaries of this empirical
analysis. First, though there is hardly any effect of financial variables on overall
U.S. import and export volumes in each sector, financial variables could have been
partly responsible for collapses in bilateral trade from individual countries in particular sectors. This possibility is consistent with the results of Chor and Manova
(2010), who found that countries experiencing greater credit contractions
reduced their exports to the United States disproportionately in financially
dependent sectors. These results point out that when one aggregates across partner countries up to sector level, the impact of financial factors on trade volumes
disappears.
In light of historical experience, this finding is not surprising. Relative to the
level of economic activity, the fall in U.S. trade during the 2001 recession was
almost as large as in 2008–09 (Levchenko, Lewis, and Tesar 2010). However, the
2001 recession was not accompanied by a contraction in credit, suggesting that
other mechanisms are probably responsible for falls in cross-border trade during
economic downturns.
Second, although the United States is widely seen as the epicenter of the financial crisis, its financial system is nonetheless one of the deepest and most resilient
in the world. Thus, even if financial factors had no effect on U.S. trade, these factors could have been much more important in other countries with weaker
financial systems. Indeed, in a wide sample of countries, past banking crises did
affect international trade flows (Iacovone and Zavacka 2009).
Third, even if financial characteristics were found to have a significant impact
on international trade volumes, such a result would not necessarily be evidence of
financial factors in international trade specifically because production may have
fallen by just as much in each sector. Thus, a conclusive test of the role of financial
variables in the trade collapse would have to find that financial factors were
responsible for changes in trade over and above the change in output. This critique
applies also to the other existing studies of finance and trade, though it is less of a
problem for the negative results here because a robust effect is not found even on
unadjusted trade volumes.
Notes
1. Data were obtained on all firms in Compustat from 2000 to 2008. These ratios were computed
for each firm in each quarter, and the median value was taken for each firm (across all the quarters for
which data are available). The median value across firms is then taken in each industry. Medians are
taken to reduce the impact of outliers, which tend to be large in firm-level data. Taking means instead
leaves the results unchanged. Because coverage is uneven across sectors, trade credit intensity is calculated over at least 10 firms. This implies that sometimes the level of variation is at the five-, four-, and
even three-digit level, although the trade data are at the six-digit NAICS level of disaggregation. See
Levchenko, Lewis, and Tesar (2010) for more details.
The Role of Trade Finance in the U.S. Trade Collapse: A Skeptic’s View
147
2. The authors are grateful to Davin Chor and Kalina Manova for sharing the interbank rate data
used in Chor and Manova 2010.
3. The authors use 2007 data collected by the U.S. Census Bureau and made available by Peter
Schott on his website: http://www.som.yale.edu/faculty/pks4/sub_international.htm.
4. The authors are grateful to David Hummels and Georg Schaur for computing these measures
using their ocean shipping time data.
References
Amiti, Mary, and David E. Weinstein. 2009. “Exports and Financial Shocks.” Discussion Paper 7590,
Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Auboin, Marc. 2009. “Restoring Trade Finance: What the G20 Can Do.” In The Collapse of Global Trade,
Murky Protectionism, and the Crisis: Recommendations for the G20, ed. Richard Baldwin and Simon
Evenett, 75–80. VoxEU.org, E-book. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
BEA (U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis). 2002. U.S. 2002 Benchmark Input-Output Database. BEA,
Washington, DC. http://www.bea.gov/industry/io_benchmark.htm.
Broda, Christian, and David Weinstein. 2006. “Globalization and the Gains from Variety.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (2): 541–85.
Chor, Davin, and Kalina Manova. 2010. “Off the Cliff and Back? Credit Conditions and International
Trade during the Global Financial Crisis.” Working Paper 16174, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, MA.
Hummels, David L. 2007. “Transportation Costs and International Trade in the Second Era of Globalization.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (3): 131–54.
Hummels, David L., and Georg Schaur. 2010. “Hedging Price Volatility Using Fast Transport.” Journal
of International Economics 82 (1): 15–25.
Iacovone, Leonardo, and Veronika Zavacka. 2009. “Banking Crises and Exports: Lessons from the Past.”
Policy Research Working Paper 5016, World Bank, Washington, DC.
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2009. “Survey of Private Sector Trade Credit Developments.”
Memorandum, IMF, Washington, DC.
Levchenko, Andrei A., Logan T. Lewis, and Linda L. Tesar. 2010. “The Collapse of International Trade
during the 2008–2009 Crisis: In Search of the Smoking Gun.” IMF Economic Review 58 (2): 214–53.
Love, Inessa, Lorenzo A. Preve, and Virginia Sarria-Allende. 2007. “Trade Credit and Bank Credit:
Evidence from Recent Financial Crises.” Journal of Financial Economics 83(2): 453–69.
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. 1998. “Financial Dependence and Growth.” The American
Economic Review 88 (3): 559–86.
8
Trade Finance in Africa:
A Survey of Firms
John Humphrey
Over the past two decades, development policy has encouraged producers in
developing countries to export labor-intensive manufactures and nontraditional agricultural exports as an effective means of reducing poverty. How did
these industries fare in the wake of the 2008–09 global crisis? Given the
unprecedented financial nature of this crisis and its impact through the banking
system, were exporters from low-income countries hit by cuts in the finance
needed for trade?
Concern has been expressed about this issue by trade specialists and policy
makers from a wide range of international organizations. The final communiqué
of the April 2009 G-20 London Summit identified withdrawal of trade credit as a
factor exacerbating trade declines, and the G-20 leaders committed $250 billion to
support trade finance. Many commentators welcomed this announcement, but
notes of skepticism have also been registered. For example, economist Richard
Baldwin, policy director of the Centre for Economic Policy Research, has suggested that expanding trade finance is an easy option that encounters little political opposition (Baldwin 2009). In fact, whether trade finance has a discernible
effect on levels of trade—and to what extent—is far from clear, as is whether
This paper was written with financial support from the U.K. Department for International Development. Paul Kamau at the Institute for Development Studies, University of Nairobi, and Steve Homer at
Biospartners (www.biospartners.co.uk) interviewed the companies. The author is also grateful to Ian
Sayers at the International Trade Centre in Geneva for providing information about trade credit issues
for developing-country exporters.
149
150
Trade Finance during the Great Trade Collapse
exporters from the poorest countries are affected to the same extent as those in
more-developed countries.
This chapter provides some evidence about whether export-oriented garment
production and high-value export horticulture in Sub-Saharan Africa have experienced problems in obtaining trade finance. The findings are based on telephone
interviews with companies in these two sectors of the African export market.
Trade Finance and How Firms Use it for Trade
Trade finance can take many forms. For simplification, this chapter focuses on
three types, as shown in table 8.1: letters of credit (LCs), domestic bank lending,
and trade credit.
LCs are specifically designed to facilitate trade by providing both finance and
assurances about payment to the exporting company. LCs require confidence and
liquidity to be maintained at various points along the chain of payment—from
the importer to the issuing bank, to the advising or confirming bank, and ultimately to the exporter.
The other two forms of trade finance are extensions of credit facilities that
operate in domestic economies. Companies may use domestic bank lending to
finance both capital investment and working capital. Such lending can be used to
facilitate trade. Similarly, firms extend credit to each other when payment takes
place before or after receipt of goods. Such credit is widely used in domestic transactions. Firms that have well-developed trading relationships may adopt the same
practice. To the extent that sophisticated global value chains linking firms in different countries often involve repeat transactions and long-term relationships,
conducting trade on these terms is not uncommon.
Policy Makers’ Concerns
The possible impact of the global financial crisis on trade finance and the capacity
of developing-country exporters to finance their trade became a salient issue in
the final few months of 2008. The International Chamber of Commerce argued
that uncertainties in global markets were leading firms to be more risk-averse,
shifting from open-account trading to LCs, while financial markets themselves
were providing less trade finance (ICC 2008). These concerns were taken up by
World Trade Organization (WTO) Director-General Pascal Lamy, who
announced the formation of a WTO task force to monitor the issue. The Institute
of International Finance suggested that private financial flows to emerging markets were falling dramatically (IIF 2009). Anecdotal evidence also emerged about
trade credit drying up, international banks becoming less willing to lend, and the