Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (5.99 MB, 831 trang )
Introduction to Part 3
A
fter I completed my 1976 paper dealing with the correlation between
schooling and adult health, I turned to the determinants of infant and
child health. The last three papers in the previous section are examples of my
work in that area. Those three papers, however, focus on the effects of parents’
schooling. The five papers in the current section are much broader. Although
they all deal with infant health, they employ a rich analytical framework in
which my demand for health model is combined with economic models of the
family developed most notably by Gary S. Becker and H. Gregg Lewis (1973),
Robert J. Willis (1973), and Becker (1981). In these models, parents maximize
a utility function that depends on their own consumption, the number of children,
and the quality of each child. It is natural to associate infants’ health with their
quality and thus to “marry” an economic approach to the family with an economic
approach to the demand for health.
Why did I decide to conduct a series of studies of the determinants of infant
mortality after I completed my last paper that employed measures of child health
beyond the first year of life in 1981 (Shakotko, Edwards and Grossman—the
second paper in the previous section)? One reason is that in the United States
and the rest of the developed world, the infant mortality rate is much higher
than child and teenage mortality rates—thirteen times greater than the largest
of these rates in the United States in 2013. Moreover, adult age-specific death
297
|
I N T R O D U C T I O N T O PA R T 3
rates do not exceed the infant mortality rate until the rate at ages fifty-five to
fifty-nine (Xu, Murphy, Kochanek, and Bastian 2016). In addition, relatively
high infant mortality rates in areas within a given country signal poor health in
all segments of the population (Fuchs 1983).
A second set of factors revolves around trends in the U.S. infant mortality
rate between the mid-1950s and the early 1980s and the relative impacts of public policies, programs, and advances in medical technology in explaining these
trends. During the period at issue, the infant mortality rate was characterized by
a decade of relative stability followed by almost two decades of rapid decline.
The rate fell by only 0.6 percent per year compounded annually between 1955
and 1964. By contrast, infant mortality dropped by 4.5 percent per year (compounded annually) between 1964 and 1982.
The period beginning in 1964 witnessed the legalization and diffusion of
abortion, the widespread adoption of oral and intrauterine contraceptive techniques, and dramatic advances in neonatal science. It also witnessed the introduction and rapid growth of programs associated with President Lyndon B.
Johnson’s War on Poverty: Medicaid, federally subsidized maternal and infant
care projects and community health centers (hereafter community health projects), federally subsidized family planning services for low-income women,
and the Special Supplemental Food Program for Women, Infants, and Children
(WIC program).1 Although other researchers had pointed to these developments
in explanations of the acceleration in the downward trend in infant mortality,
the question had not been studied in a multivariate context prior to my work.
The infant mortality rate is defined as deaths of infants within the first year
of life per thousand live births and has two components. Neonatal deaths pertain to deaths within the first twenty-seven days of life, and postneonatal deaths
occur from the twenty-eighth through the 364th day of life. Low birth weight
(weight less than 2,500 grams or less than 5.5 pounds) and prematurity (gestational age of less than thirty-seven weeks) are the two most important proximate
causes of infant and especially of neonatal mortality. These outcomes, particularly neonatal mortality and low birth weight, are featured in this section.
The first two papers in this section are motivated by the importance of
infant mortality as a key health indicator, by its trends between the mid-1950s
and the early 1980s, and by the role of the developments just mentioned in
those trends. My colleagues and I capitalize on variations in key determinants
of neonatal mortality at a moment in time (1971 in the first paper and 1977 in
the second) among counties of the United States to estimate the relative effects
of each one and their contributions to the decline in that rate (Grossman and
Jacobowitz 1981; Corman and Grossman 1985; Corman, Joyce, and Grossman
1987). We focus on neonatal mortality because the neonatal mortality rate was
D E T E R M I N A N T S O F I N F A N T H E A LT H
|
298
twice as large as the postneonatal mortality rate in 1982, and the former rate fell
much faster than the latter rate beginning in 1964. Hence, the decline in neonatal mortality rate accounted for almost 80 percent of the decline in the infant
mortality rate. Both papers apply estimated coefficients to trends in abortion
availability or use, public program availability or use, and neonatal intensive
care availability, to explain the downward trend in neonatal mortality from 1964
through the late 1970s or early 1980s.
Results in the two papers point to the growth in legal abortions as the single most important factor in reductions in white and black neonatal mortality
rates. Increases in hospitals with neonatal intensive care units also have sizable
effects for infants of both races. The extrapolations also point to the relevance of
Medicaid, organized family planning clinics, the WIC program, and community
health projects in accounting for reductions in the black rate. With the exception
of community health projects, all these factors also are relevant for whites.
I continued to work on infant health outcomes because of the availability of
data to estimate both health production functions and health demand functions.
Thus I had the opportunity to make important methodological contributions to
the literature on the determinants of health outcomes as well as to make important empirical contributions. In my economic formulation of the determinants
of health in my 1972 Journal of Political Economy (Grossman 1972a) paper
and in my 1972 National Bureau of Economic Research monograph (Grossman
1972b), I drew a distinction between these two outcome equations. The health
production function relates health to a set of endogenous inputs or choice variables including medical care services, diet, and exercise, as well as exogenous
determinants of the efficiency of the production process such as age and formal schooling completed. The health demand function relates health to income,
wage rates, input prices, and efficiency variables. It is obtained by replacing
the endogenous variables by their exogenous determinants and for that reason
is a reduced form equation.2 On the other hand, the production function is a
structural equation because endogenous variables appear on its right-hand side.
In my NBER monograph and my 1976 paper on the correlation between
health and schooling (Grossman 1976—the first paper in part 2), I focused
on the estimation of health demand functions as opposed to health production functions. I did so because unobserved biological factors, such as an individual’s exogenous health endowment and endowed rate of depreciation, and
hard-to-measure inputs, such as the avoidance of stress, can play major roles in
the determination of health outcomes. If an individual’s behavior is shaped in
part by knowledge of his or her endowments or if the unmeasured endogenous
inputs are correlated with the included inputs, then estimation of the health
technology will be biased and inconsistent.
299
|
I N T R O D U C T I O N T O PA R T 3
In the specific case of infant health outcomes, women who anticipate a
problematic birth outcome based on conditions unknown to the researcher may
seek out more remedial medical care, whereas women with positive expectations seek out less. This adverse selection in input use is emphasized by Mark
Rosenzweig and T. Paul Shultz (1983). It will understate the effect of, for example, the receipt of prenatal medical care early in the pregnancy on birth weight
or survival. Rosenzweig and Schultz use adverse selection to justify the estimation of birth weight production functions by two-stage least squares. In their
specification, delay in the receipt of prenatal care, maternal smoking during
pregnancy, previous number of live births, and mother’s age at birth are treated
as endogenous inputs in a micro level dataset. Hope Corman, Theodore J. Joyce,
and I use the same argument to fit neonatal mortality rate production functions
in the third paper in this section (Corman, Joyce, and Grossman 1987). These
functions differ from the neonatal mortality rate reduced form or demand function estimates in Corman and Grossman (1985). The primary distinction is that
county-specific input availability measures in the 1985 paper are used as instruments for input use measures in the 1987 paper. Results in our 1987 paper and
related results by Joyce (1987) and by Rosenzweig and Schultz (1983) point to
larger input use effects when the endogeneity of use is taken into account by
estimating production functions by two-stage least squares.
Adverse selection in input use, is not, however, the only source of bias
due to selection. The efficacy of prenatal care, for example, may be seriously
overstated if early care is but one form of healthy behavior. Pregnant women
who initiate care promptly may eat more nutritiously, engage in the appropriate
exercise, and use fewer drugs and other potentially harmful substances than
women who begin care later. The omission of these hard-to-measure inputs
tends to overestimate the impact of early prenatal care on infant health—an
example of favorable selection.
Moreover, the resolution of pregnancy itself may be characterized by
self-selection. With regard to this outcome, selection is favorable if women
whose fetuses have poor health endowments are more likely to obtain an abortion or if women who desire to make large investments in their infants are more
likely to give birth. On the other hand, selection is adverse if women who make
relatively small investments are more likely to give birth.
The use of an instrumental variable approach to correct for self-selection
in input use presupposes that this decision is characterized by adverse selection
and ignores the problem of self-selection in the resolution of pregnancies. In the
fourth paper in this section, Joyce and I (Grossman and Joyce 1990) approach
the problem differently and somewhat more generally. Following James J. Heckman (1979), we treat the estimation of infant health production functions and
D E T E R M I N A N T S O F I N F A N T H E A LT H
|
300
prenatal medical care demand functions as a general problem in self-selection.
Specifically, we test whether women who give birth represent a random draw
from the population of women who become pregnant. The widespread use of
induced abortion since its legalization by the Supreme Court in 1973 has permitted much greater choice in the number and timing of births. Thus the extent to
which a failure to incorporate the choice-based nature of micro vital records into
estimates of infant health production functions may bias the parameters of this
function is potentially large. Joyce and I hypothesize that the unobserved factors
that impact on the decision to give birth not only affect pregnancy outcomes but
also condition the behavior of women who choose to give birth during pregnancy
as well.
Our study is based on a cohort of pregnant women in New York City in
1984. In that year, 45 percent of all pregnancies to New York City residents
ended in induced abortions. We estimate a three-equation model. The first equation is the probability of giving birth, given that a woman is pregnant. With this
as our criterion equation, we test for self-selection in the infant health (measured
by birth weight) production function and in the prenatal medical care demand
function. Empirically, our estimates differ from those obtained by Rosenzweig
and Schultz (1983) because they use micro vital records on live births alone.
Not only does our methodology obviate the need to assert a priori whether
adverse or favorable selection is dominant, but the sign pattern of the residual
covariances indicates which type of selection characterizes both the decision to
give birth and the decision to initiate prenatal care promptly.
Because our framework includes an implicit equation for the probability
of becoming pregnant, we incorporate induced abortion as an alternative to
traditional methods of contraception into economic models of fertility control
(for example, Michael and Willis 1976; Hotz and Miller 1988). These models
emphasize the use of contraception to reduce the uncertainty associated with the
number and timing of births.
Induced abortion eliminates much of this uncertainty at a positive price.
By assuming that the prices of contraception and abortion have unmeasured
components that vary among women, we enrich the theoretical literature on
the optimal number and quality of children (for example, Becker and Lewis;
1973; Willis 1973) and gain a better understanding of the earliest indicator of
child quality—infant health—and the resources allocated to its production. In
particular, we show that the prices of contraception and abortion, as well as the
health endowment of the fetus, simultaneously influence decisions with regard
to pregnancy resolutions and input selection.
Joyce and I find strong evidence of selectivity bias in the birth weight
production function and prenatal demand equation among blacks but no
301
|
I N T R O D U C T I O N T O PA R T 3
evidence of such bias among whites. For the former group, the results suggest that the unobserved factors that raise the probability of giving birth are
positively correlated with the unobserved factors that decrease delay in the
initiation of prenatal care and increase birth weight. The sign patterns among
the residual covariances are consistent with a model that emphasizes the cost
of contraceptives. In particular, black women for whom the shadow price
of contraception is relatively high are more likely to abort a pregnancy than
their counterparts who face a lower shadow price and whose pregnancies
were more likely to have been planned. The latter group should consume
more prenatal care (delay less) and invest in other healthy behaviors that
improve birth weight.
One explanation for the racial differences with respect to selectivity bias is
that the shadow price of contraception is greater for blacks than it is for whites.
Further, the shadow price is apt to vary more among blacks than it does among
whites. Racial differences in contraceptive use and abortion in the 1980s and in
more recent years are consistent with this interpretation (Guttmacher Institute
2015, 2016).
The results for blacks indicate that women who aborted would have given
birth to lighter infants if they had selected the birth option and if they had had
the same mean values of the observed variables in the birth weight equation as
women who actually gave birth. One way to gauge the magnitude of the effect
is to compare it to that of an observed risk factor for birth outcomes. Among
blacks, complications due to maternal cigarette smoking reduce birth weight
by 187 grams or by 5.8 percent relative to a mean of 3,184 for pregnancies not
complicated by smoking. On the other hand, potential mean birth weight in the
abortion sample falls short of birth weight in the birth sample by 116 grams
due to unobserved inputs alone. This amounts to a differential of 3.7 percent
relative to the observed mean of 3,173 for all black women in the birth sample.
Thus the impact of unobserved healthy behaviors is almost two-thirds as large
in absolute value as the effect of smoking. Finally, if we allow for differences in
both observed and unobserved characteristics, the potential mean birth weight
of women who aborted would have 140 grams less than the observed mean birth
weight. This makes the impacts of unobserved healthy behaviors almost threefourths as large as that of smoking.
As I pointed out in the introduction to this book, Joseph P. Newhouse has
characterized the literature in health economics as consisting of two largely
nonoverlapping streams: one dealing with the determinants of the health of
the population and the other dealing with markets for health insurance and
medical services. By focusing on the impact of the introduction of National
Health Insurance (NHI) in Taiwan in 1995 on birth outcomes, Shin-Yi Chou,
D E T E R M I N A N T S O F I N F A N T H E A LT H
|
302
Jin-Tan Liu, and I contribute to both streams in the last paper in this section
(Chou, Grossman, and Liu 2014). There is enormous interest in the impacts
of NHI on health outcomes, but the very nature of this intervention, whereby
entire nations are covered universally, makes it difficult to estimate the health
impacts of the change. The experience of Taiwan, however, provides a potential laboratory for overcoming these limitations. Prior to NHI, government
workers possessed health insurance policies that covered prenatal medical
care, newborn deliveries, neonatal care, and medical care services received
by their children beyond the first month of life. Private sector industrial workers and farmers lacked this coverage. All households received coverage for
the services just mentioned as of March 1995. Therefore, the introduction
of NHI constitutes a natural experiment with treatment and control groups
that form the basis of our empirical design. The former group consists of
nongovernment-employed households, and the latter group consists of government-employed households. We expect that increases in infant health after
the introduction of NHI in the treatment group will exceed corresponding
increases in the control group.
Unlike in the United States, the postneonatal mortality rate in Taiwan is
higher than the neonatal mortality rate. Moreover, stringent requirements for
reporting births introduced in 1994 produced artificial upward trends in early
infant deaths. For those reasons, we limit our analysis to postneonatal mortality.
The introduction of NHI led to reductions in this rate for infants born in
farm households but not for infants born in private sector households. For the
former group, the rate fell by between 0.3 and 0.6 deaths per thousand survivors
or by between 8 and 16 percent. A large decline of between 3.4 and 6.8 deaths
occurred for preterm infants—a drop of between 20 and 41 percent. In the preNHI period, the postneonatal mortality rate of farm infants was approximately
23 percent higher than the corresponding rate of private sector infants. Hence,
our findings are consistent with the notion that the provision of health insurance to previously uninsured infants has larger effects on those born in poor
health than on others. Our result that the effects of NHI rise in absolute value
as the availability of medical care resources in the infant’s county of residence
rises is evidence that increases in medical care services received by infants
made eligible for insurance coverage by NHI may account for at least part
of the improvements in health outcomes that we observe. Farm families have
lower levels of health, education, and income than private sector families and
premature and low-weight infants are in worse health than other infants. Thus,
taken as a set, our findings suggest that health insurance improves infant health
outcomes of population subgroups characterized by low levels of education,
income, and health.
303
|
I N T R O D U C T I O N T O PA R T 3
NOTES
1. Federally subsidized maternal and infant care projects were authorized by the Social
Security Act of 1935 but were greatly expanded by the War on Poverty. Community
health centers, originally termed neighborhood health centers, were started by the Office
of Economic Opportunity as part of the War on Poverty.
2. Of course, the papers in part 2 and the references in that part question the endogeneity of
schooling.
REFERENCES
Becker, Gary S. 1981. A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Becker, Gary S., and H. Gregg Lewis. 1973. “On the Interaction Between the Quantity and
Quality of Children.” Journal of Political Economy 81(2, pt. 2): S279–S288.
Chou, Shin-Yi, Michael Grossman, and Jin-Tan Liu. 2014. “The Impact of National Health
Insurance on Birth Outcomes: A Natural Experiment in Taiwan.” Journal of Development
Economics 111(November): 75–91.
Corman, Hope, and Michael Grossman. 1985. “Determinants of Neonatal Mortality Rates in
the U.S.: A Reduced Form Model.” Journal of Health Economics 4(3): 213–236.
Corman, Hope, Theodore J. Joyce, and Michael Grossman. 1987. “Birth Outcome Production
Functions in the U.S.” Journal of Human Resources 22(3): 339–360.
Fuchs, Victor R. 1983. How We Live: An Economic Perspective on Americans from Birth to
Death. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Grossman, Michael. 1972a. “On the Concept of Health Capital and the Demand for Health.”
Journal of Political Economy 80(2): 223–255.
——. 1972b. The Demand for Health: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation. New York:
Columbia University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.
——. 1976. “The Correlation Between Health and Schooling.” In Household Production and
Consumption, ed. Nestor E. Terleckyj. Studies in Income and Wealth, Volume 40, by the
Conference on Research in Income and Wealth. New York: Columbia University Press for
the National Bureau of Economic Research, 147–211.
Grossman, Michael, and Steven Jacobowitz. 1981. “Variations in Infant Mortality Rates
among Counties of the United States: The Roles of Public Policies and Programs.”
Demography 18(4): 695–713.
Grossman, Michael, and Theodore J. Joyce. 1990. “Unobservables, Pregnancy Resolutions,
and Birth Weight Production Functions in New York City.” Journal of Political Economy
98 (5, pt. 1): 983–1007.
Guttmacher Institute. 2015. Contraceptive Use in the United States http://www.guttmacher
.org/pubs/fb_contr_use.pdf.
Guttmacher Institute. 2016. Facts on Induced Abortion in the United States. http://www
.guttmacher.org/pubs/fb_induced_abortion.html.Heckman, James J. 1979. “Sample
Selection Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica 47(1): 153–161.
D E T E R M I N A N T S O F I N F A N T H E A LT H
|
304
Hotz, V. Joseph, and Robert A. Miller. 1988. “An Empirical Analysis of Life Cycle Fertility
and Female Labor Supply.” Econometrica 56(1): 91–118.
Joyce, Theodore J. 1987. “The Impact of Induced Abortion on Black and White Birth Outcomes.” Demography 24(2): 229–244.
Michael, Robert T., and Robert J. Willis. 1976. “Contraception and Fertility: Household Production Under Uncertainty.” In Household Production and Consumption, ed. Nestor E.
Terleckyj. Studies in Income and Wealth, Volume 40, by the Conference on Research in
Income and Wealth. New York: Columbia University Press for the National Bureau of
Economic Research, 27–93.
Rosenzweig, Mark, and T. Paul Shultz. 1983. “Estimating a Household Production Function:
Heterogeneity, the Demand for Health Inputs, and Their Effects on Birth Weight.” Journal
of Political Economy 91(5): 723–746.
Shakotko, Robert A., Linda N. Edwards, and Michael Grossman. 1981. “An Exploration of
the Dynamic Relationship Between Health and Cognitive Development in Adolescence.”
In Contributions to Economic Analysis: Health, Economics, and Health Economics,
ed. Jacques van der Gaag and Mark Perlman. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing,
305–328.
Willis, Robert J. 1973. “A New Approach to the Economics of Fertility Behavior.” Journal of
Political Economy 81(2, pt. 2): S14–S64.
Xu, Jiaquan, Sherry L. Murphy, Kenneth D. Kochanek, and Brigham A. Bastian. 2016.
“Deaths: Final Data for 2013.” National Vital Statistics Report 64(2). Hyattsville, MD:
National Center for Health Statistics.
Variations in Infant Mortality Rates
SEVEN
among Counties of the United States
The Roles of Public Policies
and Programs
Michael Grossman and Steven Jacobowitz
ABSTRACT
The purpose of this paper is to shed light on the causes of the rapid decline in the
infant mortality rate in the United States in the period after 1963. The roles of
four public policies are considered: Medicaid, subsidized family planning services
for low-income women, maternal and infant care projects, and the legalization
of abortion. The most striking finding is that the increase in the legal abortion
rate is the single most important factor in reductions in both white and nonwhite
neonatal mortality rates. Not only does the growth in abortion dominate the other
public policies, but it also dominates schooling and poverty.
From 1964 to 1977, the infant mortality rate in the United States declined at an
annually compounded rate of 4.4 percent per year. This was an extremely rapid
rate of decline compared to the figure of 0.6 percent per year from 1955 to 1964.
The reduction in mortality proceeded at an even faster pace in the 1970s than in
the late 1960s (5.2 percent per year from 1971 to 1977 versus 3.8 percent per
year from 1964 to 1971).1
The period from 1964 to 1977 witnessed the introduction of Medicaid,
maternal and infant care projects, federally subsidized family planning services for low-income women, the legalization of abortion, and the widespread
D E T E R M I N A N T S O F I N F A N T H E A LT H
|
306
adoption of oral and intrauterine contraceptive techniques. These developments have been pointed to in discussions of the cause of the acceleration in
the downward trend in infant mortality (for example, Eisner et al. 1978; Lee
et al. 1980), but the question has not been studied in a multivariate context.
Moreover, the relative contribution of each factor has not been quantified. The
purpose of this paper is to estimate the impacts of public policies and programs
on infant mortality.
1. ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK
Economic models of the family and household production developed by
Becker and Lewis (1973) and Willis (1973) provide a fruitful theoretical
framework to generate multivariate health outcome functions and to assess the
roles of social programs and policies in these functions. Ben-Porath (1973),
Ben-Porath and Welch (1976), Williams (1976), and Lewit (1977) have utilized the economic model of the family to study theoretically and empirically
the determinants of birth outcomes. Following these authors, we assume that
the parents’ utility function depends on their own consumption, the number of births, and the survival probability. Both the number of births and
the survival probability are endogenous variables. In particular, the survival
probability production function depends upon endogenous inputs of medical
care, nutrition, and the own time of the mother. In addition, the production
function is affected by the reproductive efficiency of the mother and by other
aspects of her efficiency in household production. Given the considerable
body of evidence that education raises market and nonmarket productivity,
one would expect more educated mothers to be more efficient producers of
surviving infants.
The above model calls attention to the important determinants of the survival probability and its complement, the infant mortality rate. In general, this
set of determinants is similar to that used in multivariate studies of infant mortality with different and fewer theoretical points of departure (for example,
Fuchs 1974; Williams 1974; Brooks 1978; Gortmaker 1979). Moreover, the
model provides a ready structure within which to interpret the effects of public
programs and policies on infant mortality.2 Thus, Medicaid and maternal and
infant care projects lower the direct and indirect costs3 of obtaining prenatal
and obstetrical care, which should increase the likelihood of a favorable birth
outcome and lower infant mortality. Federal subsidization of family planning
services, abortion reform, and the diffusion of oral and intrauterine contraceptive techniques (the pill and the IUD) reduce the costs of birth control and