Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (5.15 MB, 255 trang )
2. CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
A
ll OECD countries are seeking to better address environmental challenges. While there
are many ways to do this, one of the most interesting is the movement towards a “greening”
of government actions. Government fiscal policy – on both the revenue and expenditure side
– has a large impact on the economy. Movements towards a more environmentally conscious
approach to fiscal policy can translate into changed behaviours within the larger economy.
In particular, the tax system is seen as a medium where governments can have particular
influence on the decisions of firms and individuals. Governments have long been conscious of
the impact of the tax system on employment, business formation and expansion, and
consumption patterns and thus have generally tried to raise revenues without distorting
consumption patterns or inhibiting investment decisions. Many of the same ideas can be used
in the field of environmentally related taxation; however, a goal of environmentally related
taxation is to skew consumption and production patterns and reduce the size of the tax base,
which is quite different from the goals of most types of taxation.
2.1. Revenues from environmentally related taxation across countries
While the concept of environmentally related taxes has become more a part of
governments’ policy dialogue in recent decades, all OECD countries raise revenues through
environmentally related taxation and have for many years. Given the definition outlined in
Box 2.1, this encompasses a wide range of taxes, such as excise taxes on fossil fuels, motor
vehicle registration taxes, taxes on water pollution and waste. Significant differences do
exist across countries that reflect historical realties and variances within tax systems.
Figure 2.1 shows that environmentally related taxation is a small, but not insignificant,
revenue source for governments, averaging around 2% of gross domestic product (GDP).
It is clear that Denmark and the Netherlands lead OECD countries in revenue
generated from environmentally related taxation and their shares have been strong over
the twelve-year period, contrasted against the general decline for OECD countries. One
feature that stands out is the significant geographical differences present. All four
countries in the Americas generally have the lowest levels of revenues derived from
environmentally related taxation. Three of the four OECD countries in the Pacific have
levels below that of the arithmetic average. At the top end, European countries have the
most significant revenue levels from environmentally related tax bases. This is consistent
with European countries’ relatively high overall tax revenue-to-GDP ratios. In the case of
Denmark, its tax revenue-to-GDP ratio is the highest in the OECD.
An interesting case is that of Mexico, where the revenues from environmentally
related taxation were actually negative in 2008. As with most countries, the vast majority
of revenues are normally derived from taxes on motor fuels. The Mexican fuel tax has a
unique structure in that it can act inversely to rapid changes to oil prices. In 2002, oil prices
were quite low, thereby resulting in relatively high tax rates. By 2008, however, oil prices
had increased significantly, resulting in the effective fuel tax rate, and therefore the tax
revenue, actually turning negative.
32
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
2.
CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
Box 2.1. Definition of environmentally related taxation
The OECD, the International Energy Agency (IEA) and the European Commission have
agreed to define environmentally related taxes as any compulsory, unrequited payment to
general government levied on tax bases deemed to be of partic
relevance. The relevant tax bases include energy products, motor vehicles, waste,
measured or estimated emissions, natural resources, etc. Taxes are unrequited in the
sense that benefits provided by government to taxpayers are not normally in proportion to
their payments. Requited compulsory payments to the government that are levied more or
less in proportion to services provided (e.g. the amount of wastes collected and treated) can
be labelled as fees and charges. The term levy covers both taxes and fees/charges.
Creating any definition of environmentally related taxes is inherently problematic. Taxes
may have been implemented for a number of reasons, most likely general revenue-raising,
with little to no consideration for the environment. Moreover, some taxes have likely been
implemented without stringent assessment of the costs and damages of the pollution,
leading to non-optimal rates. Attempting to differentiate taxes based on motivation of the
government or exclude some taxes because of their design would, of course, pose
significant challenges. Therefore, a broad definition has been used that considers only the
type of tax base, not the intention or appropriateness of the instrument.
It should be noted that broad-based taxes, such as value added taxes (VAT), whose tax bases
include those which may be environmentally related, are not included as environmentally
related taxation in this report. In addition, revenues from the sale of tradable permits and
revenues derived from natural resource royalties are not included.
Figure 2.1. Revenues from environmentally related taxation as percentage of GDP
1996
2002
2008
Per cent of GDP
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
Un
M
i t e ex
d ico
St
at
es
Ch
N e C a il e
w na
Ze da
al
an
Ja d
pa
Sp n
a
Fr in
Au anc
st e
ra
Po li a
Sl
l
ov B e and
ak lg
Re ium
pu
bl
S w Ic e i c
i t z land
er
la
Gr n d
Ge eec
rm e
Un
i te Es any
d ton
Ki ia
ng 1
do
Ir e m
l
No and
rw
Lu Au ay
xe s t
m ria
bo
ur
Ko g
re
a
It a
Sw ly
e
Po den
r tu
Cz S g
e c lo al
h ve
Re ni
pu a
b
F i li c
n
Hu l a nd
ng
a
Is r y
ra
Tu el 2
De r ke
N e nm y
th ar
Ar
er k
la
ith
nd
m
s
W et
ei ic
gh av
t e er
d ag
av e
er
ag
e
-2
1. Estonia is an accession country to the OECD and has not been included in the averages.
2. The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use of such data by
the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the
terms of international law.
Source: OECD/EEA database on instruments for environmental policy.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317179
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
33
2. CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
Also when analysing the environmentally related tax revenue against total tax
revenues, which reflects the importance of the revenues to overall government budgets,
much the same trend can be seen in Figure 2.2. The geographic delineations are somewhat
less pronounced and the cross-country differences appear less severe. The reliance on
environmentally related taxation in some countries, such as Korea, which does
high tax-to-GDP ratio, is more pronounced. Turkey stands out for having significantly
increased its share of tax revenues from environmentally related bases such that these tax
revenues now account for close to 15% of overall tax revenue, well above all other OECD
members. This approach is part of a larger tax reform in Turkey to raise additional rev
from consumption and less from other sources, such as income and corporate taxes. Higher
fuel taxes have been a deliberate part of their national development plans which seek
development in a more sustainable manner, resulting in some of the highest motor fuel
prices among OECD countries. On the other hand, the relative level of environmentally
related taxation over the ten-year period in countries such as Greece, Mexico and Portugal
has been significantly reduced.
Figure 2.2. Revenues from environmentally related taxation as percentage of total tax revenues
1996
2002
2008
Per cent of total tax revenue
15
12
9
6
3
0
-3
-6
Un
M
i t e ex
Ne d S ico
w t at
Ze es
al
a
C a nd
na
Fr da
a
Be nce
lg
iu
m
Ch
il e
Sp
Ic a in
el
S w and
ed
Au en
s
No tr ia
rw
Po ay
la
n
Ja d
pa
n
Ge It al
rm y
a
F i ny
nl
an
G d
Sl A r e e
ov u c e
Un a k R s tr a
i te ep li a
d ub
K
l
S w in gd i c
i o
Lu t ze m
xe r l a
m nd
bo
E s ur g
to
Sl ni a 1
ov
Hu eni a
n
Cz P ga
ec or r y
h tu
Re g a
pu l
b
Ir e l i c
De l an
nm d
ar
Ko k
re
N e Is a
th r a
er el
la
n
Ar
Tu ds
ith
rk
m
ey
W et
ei ic
gh av
t e er
d ag
av e
er
ag
e
-9
1. Estonia is an accession country to the OECD and has not been included in the averages.
2. The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use of such data by
the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the
terms of international law.
Source: OECD/EEA database on instruments for environmental policy.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317198
The volatility in the figures between years can be accounted for by a number of
reasons. On the one hand, the actual level of revenues from environmentally related
taxation could have changed due to rate changes or changes in the quantity of pollutants
emitted. On the other hand, changes in other government revenues could have occurred,
such as income or corporate tax rates, or variations in the bases on which those taxes are
levied, such as an economic slowdown that could curtail corporate tax revenues.
34
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
2.
CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
Despite this volatility, there is still an overall relative decline in revenues over time, as
evidenced by the averages in Figure 2.1 and Figure 2.2. A number of issues contribute to
this trend:
●
Over this period, oil prices have risen significantly, reducing demand and thereby
contributing to downward levels of revenues from these sources compared to other parts
of the economy.
●
As the construction of environmentally related taxes – typically excise taxes – are levied
per unit of product (e.g. EUR 0.10 per litre of petrol), inflation can work to reduce the impact
of the tax over the longer term. The nominal value of the tax rate may stay the same but
the real value declines, which differs from other tax revenues that are percentage-based
(e.g. value added taxes on consumption or income tax rates). Political resistance to tax
increases can exacerbate these declines, leading to tax levels that are likely misaligned
with the initial rationale for the level of the tax rate. Years of no nominal change in the tax
rate can result in significant increases over a short period to compensate.
●
The rise of emissions trading systems (which have similar properties to taxes) have
meant that some countries are introducing these systems while simultaneously
reducing taxes on similar bases. As outlined in Section 2.5, the revenues from auctioning
tradable permits are not yet included in the figures of environmentally related taxation.
So far, such revenues are modest.
●
In the same light, some countries have moved away from taxes in favour of fees (which
are similarly not included in the above figures) on the same bases, especially in the
transportation area.
●
Finally, there is the possibility that some of the impact can be attributed to effectiveness of
the taxes themselves in reducing the amount of the pollutants (and therefore tax revenues).
As a counteracting measure, a number of European countries have instituted
inflation-adjusted tax rates. These actions remove the political necessity of instituting
inflation-related rises and create smoother tax rates across years. Denmark, for example,
as part of their 2009 budget process, instituted automatic inflation indexing of energy
(including motor fuel) taxes.
It should be noted that the level of revenues raised from environmentally related taxation
should not necessarily be taken as a measure of the “environmental friendliness” of a country
or of their overall tax system. First, taxes can be non-optimally designed such that they do not
necessarily bring about desired behaviour change, and their rates can be set non-optimally,
such that they do not necessarily reflect the environmental damage that they cause, despite
the fact that they may raise significant revenues. A number of countries have taken to making
their environmentally related taxes better designed without necessarily increasing revenues.
Additionally, countries may place a greater emphasis on the utilisation of other instruments to
address environmental challenges and thereby achieve similar environmental results without
the revenues that environmentally related taxation can generate, although often at a higher
cost than if well-designed environmentally related taxes had been used. Finally, structural
differences across countries’ economies can play a role (e.g. some countries may have more
emission intensive industries due to location-specific activities).
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
35
2. CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
2.2. Taxes on specific pollutants
Environmentally related taxes have evolved over many decades. In this timeframe,
many different events at the local and international level have impacted environmental
policy. The result is that, in most OECD countries, there exists a wide range of taxes and
charges which may not always be in line with the relevant damages. Different pollutants
result in different damages to the environment. High tax rates sometimes occur on some
more benign pollutants while more damaging pollution is not taxed. In addition, some
pollutants are taxed radically differently based on the source or emitter of the pollution.
The vast majority of environmentally related tax revenues are derived from taxes on
energy – of which taxes on motor fuel constitute nearly all of those proceeds. As seen in
Figure 2.3, the revenues from these energy taxes account for about two-thirds of the total
revenues. In addition, the “other” category, although small, has relatively grown over the
period compared to the other categories.
Figure 2.3. Composition of environmentally related tax revenues in the OECD
Energy products
Motor vehicles and transport
Other
Per cent of GDP
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Source: OECD/EEA database on instruments for environmental policy.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317217
The composition of environmentally related taxation varies across countries as well,
as seen in Figure 2.4. Countries such as Poland, the Slovak Republic and Luxembourg1 rely
heavily on energy taxes. Taxes on motor vehicles constitute a significant part for total
revenues for Denmark, the Netherlands, Ireland and Norway. Finally, the Netherlands
stands out for its relatively large usage of “other” environmentally related taxes.
2.2.1. Motor fuel and motor vehicle taxes
Motor fuel
Excise taxes on fuel have been around for many years, originally being motivated by
non-environmental needs alone (such as general revenue generation or sometimes
earmarked for specific infrastructure projects). The revenues raised from these taxes are
quite high, a result of the significant level of consumption in OECD countries. Figure 2.5
presents the different excise tax rates on petrol and diesel in OECD countries for years 2000
and 2010. Much like the overall analysis above, clear groupings by geographic area are
present. North America has the lowest petrol taxes, followed by OECD countries in Asia and
36
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
2.
CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
Figure 2.4. Composition of environmentally related tax revenues by country
Energy
Motor vehicles
Per cent of GDP (2008)
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
Un
M
i t e ex
d ico
St
at
es
Ch
N e C a il e
w na
Ze da
al
an
Ja d
pa
Sp n
a
Fr in
Au anc
st e
ra
Po li a
Sw l
i t z and
er
l
Sl
ov B e and
ak lg
Re ium
pu
b
Ic li c
el
an
Gr d
Ge eec
rm e
Un
a
i te Es ny
d ton
K i ia 1
ng
do
Ir e m
la
No nd
rw
Lu Au ay
xe s t r
m ia
bo
ur
Ko g
re
a
It a
Sw ly
e
Po den
r tu
Cz S g
e c lo al
h ven
Re i
pu a
b
F i li c
n
Hu l and
ng
a
Is r y
ra
e
Tu l 2
De r ke
N e nm y
th ar
er k
la
nd
s
Av
er
ag
e
-2
1. Estonia is an accession country to the OECD and has not been included in the average.
2. The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use of such data by
the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the
terms of international law.
Source: OECD/EEA database on instruments for environmental policy.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317236
Figure 2.5. Tax rates on motor fuel
Petrol 2010
Diesel 2010
Petrol 2000
Diesel 2000
EUR per litre
1.00
0.80
0.60
0.40
0.20
0
Un
M
i t e ex i
d co
St
at
e
Ne Ca s
w nad
Ze a
al
an
d
C
A u hil e
st
ra
Ic li a
el
an
Po d
la
n
Ja d
pa
Ko n
Es rea
to
ni
a1
Sp
Hu a in
ng
ar
Lu Au y
xe s t r
Cz m ia
ec b
h ou
Re r g
pu
Sl bli c
ov
S
Sl w i t en
ov ze i a
ak rla
Re nd
pu
bl
Is i c
ra
S w el 2
ed
Ir e e n
la
nd
It a
Be ly
lg
D e ium
nm
Po ar k
r tu
g
Fr al
an
Gr c e
ee
No ce
rw
Un
i t e F in ay
d
K i land
ng
G dom
N e er m
th an
er y
la
nd
Tu s
rk
ey
-0.20
Notes: Rates are as at 01.01.2010 and 01.01.2000 and converted using the average exchange rate for 2009. Data for the United States and
Canada include average excise taxes at the state/provincial level. VAT is not included.
1. Estonia is an accession country to the OECD.
2. The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use of such data by
the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the
terms of international law.
Source: OECD/EEA database on instruments for environmental policy.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317255
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
37
2. CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
the Pacific, with European countries having significantly higher tax rates. Compared to other
tax rates within the overall economy, the level of taxation for petrol re
very high, with the total burden typically exceeding 100% of pre-tax
should be seen in the context of the underlying price (which can vary between countries due
to factors such as transportation) and the presence of other taxes, such as VAT.
For almost all countries, tax levels on both fuels have increased over the ten-year
period, with Turkey witnessing significant increases. Iceland moved from zero taxation on
diesel in 2000 to a tax rate near parity with petrol in combination with changes in the
taxation of diesel vehicles. Greece has also seen significant increases in tax rates,
especially on petrol. These principally occurred between 2009 and 2010 as a means to help
consolidate government revenues in response to strong budget pressures. Finally, Mexico
is the only OECD member country with an effective negative excise tax rate due to high
international crude prices in 2009. It should be noted that the tax levels are the posted
(so-called “headline”) rates and do not reflect that there may be multiple rates or
exemptions for specific uses or users.
It is interesting to note, in addition, that the excise taxation levels for diesel fuel are
significantly lower than those for petrol. Only two countries – Switzerland and the
United States – have a higher level of tax for diesel than petrol; Australia and the
United Kingdom’s rates are the same for both fuel types. The majority of diesel rates are
situated within the 70-80% of petrol range, with New Zealand not levying any excise tax on
diesel.2 From an environmental point of view, this is peculiar, as diesel consumption in
vehicles has a much larger environmental impact than unleaded petrol, largely due to the
significant differences in NOx and particulate emissions. With more stringent motor
vehicle regulations, the difference is becoming less distinct. The differences in fuel taxes
can also have an important impact on consumer behaviour, as seen in Box 2.2.
Box 2.2. Turkey’s taxes on motor fuels
Turkey has the highest tax rate on petrol in OECD countries and these tax rates have
been increased significantly over the last decade. Turkey had a level of per capita
purchasing power parity in 2007 of only 37% of the OECD average, yet its level of
environmentally related taxes is among the highest in the OECD. It is interesting to
note that Turkey has increased these taxes on motor fuels alongside tax rates on many
luxury goods. Turkey’s economy is much less dependent on personal vehicles than other
OECD countries, with only 117 vehicles per 1 000 people in 2005, compared to the OECD
average of 606 vehicles per 1 000 people (World Bank). As such, fuel taxes may form a
progressive means of taxation (unlike in higher-income countries where energy taxes are
generally seen as regressive).
In Turkey, petrol is taxed significantly more than either diesel or liquefied petroleum gas
(LPG), having important influences on consumption patterns. Coupled with a lower ex-tax
price per litre of LPG, lower tax rates have encouraged a significant shift towards
LPG-fuelled vehicles. Between 2003 and 2007, the number of cars outfitted to run on LPG
more than doubled from 800 000 to over 1.8 million. There was also a significant shift in
more standard fuels, with total petrol consumption remaining quite flat while diesel
consumption increased significantly. As a percentage of GDP, petrol use declined
significantly. The trends suggest that taxes (and underlying prices) can have an important
impact on consumer behaviour.
38
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
2.
CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
Within these broad categories of petrol and diesel, tax rates also vary based on the fuel
characteristics. When leaded petrol was still widely available, governments typically taxed
this at a higher rate than unleaded petrol. In the present context, a number of countries
differentiate their tax rate based on other criteria related to the characteristics of the fuel,
such as the level of sulphur content and the proportion of renewable fuels present.
While Figure 2.5 outlines the actual level of taxes on petrol in OECD, it is difficult to
know if these are at the correct level. A multitude of factors go into determining the rate – the
environmental damage, the use of roads, the cost of vehicular accidents and the general
need for governments to raise revenues. Box 2.3 outlines what one study suggests should be
the optimal petrol tax for the American state of California.
Box 2.3. Multiple externalities and an optimal tax for California
A prescient example of the multiple externality issue is the calculation of optimal petrol
taxes. These taxes obviously have a significant environmental impact, both global and local,
although they are levied for a range of reasons. However, determining an “optimal” tax
requires looking at all the various impacts that fuel use can have. First, governments need to
raise revenue from a variety of sources to fund public services. Since economic theory
suggests that changing consumers’ preferences leads to some welfare loss, taxes should be
focused on those goods that are rather invariable to price changes – that is, those that are
price inelastic. Motor fuels meet this criterion. In addition, “optimal” fuels taxes should try
to correct negative externalities, which are unwanted effects that accrue to others from an
individual’s actions. In the case of the environment, one person’s combustion of fossil fuel
releases pollutants that negatively affect others (without them being compensated).
Therefore, taxes should encapsulate the various environmental externalities. Finally, there
are other externalities associated with motor fuels. By driving, for example, accidents occur
which impose a cost on to taxpayers and congestion reduces the welfare of other drivers. In
total, the “optimal” motor fuel tax should incorporate all these various features in the setting
of the rate. Therefore, environmentally related taxes go beyond just the environmental
considerations, since the focus is on the base.
In their analysis related to the US state of California, Lin and Prince (2009) find an
optimal tax rate for petrol of USD 0.36 per litre outside of sales taxes. Most of the tax is
based on externalities (USD 0.22 per litre), of which only USD 0.02 is for global pollution
(e.g. climate change)* and USD 0.04 is for local pollution. The rest is related to congestion,
accidents and oil dependence. The single largest component (USD 0.14 per litre) is due to
the attractiveness of taxing petrol because its demand is quite price inelastic – so-called
Ramsey taxation.
The climate change component is very small. Even using a different methodology that
placed greater emphasis on the damage from climate change would likely not have a
significant impact on the overall optimal tax rate. As a means of comparison, the current
excise tax is less than a third of this “optimal” level. While the environmental component
of the petrol tax is low, it is worth noting that when the overall excise tax rate is lower than
the optimal, there will be overconsumption, which induces excess environmental damage.
As noted in OECD (2006), the tax rates on petrol in some European countries, however, may
be above their optimal level.
* The climate change component is taken from another study. Using different values for the environmental
damage would affect the magnitude of this variable but is unlikely to have a large impact on the overall
optimal level of the tax, given its small relative contribution.
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
39
2. CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
The general increase in nominal tax rates outlined in Figure 2.5 does not address how
these taxes measure against the real impact that they have on influencing consumer
behaviour and on government revenues. Figure 2.6 shows the real percentage change of the
total tax rate on petrol (excise taxes, no VAT or general sales taxes) across OECD economies
over the period 2000-10. While several jurisdictions have seen significant increases in real
taxes on petrol, the majority have not. Australia, for example, cut its nominal rate of
taxation on petrol. The United States’ federal rate remained nearly fixed in nominal terms
over the period, while Greece significantly increased petrol taxes as a revenue raiser in at
the end of 2009. Nevertheless, these rises did not keep up with inflation, leading to
significant declines in the real effect of the tax rate. The average real change in the tax rate
on petrol over the period was –8.1% (11.0% decline in the arithmetic average).3 This, along
with rising oil prices bringing about declining consumption, can have an impact on the
total environmentally related revenues collected by governments.
Figure 2.6. Real changes in tax rates on petrol
Between 2000 and 2010
Per cent
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
-140
Gr
e
Po ec e
r tu
g
Ir e a l
la
n
Tu d
rk
S e
Ne we y
w de
Ze n
al
an
d
Ja
pa
Ge n
Lu rm
xe a n
m y
bo
ur
Un
i te Po g
la
d
K i nd
ng
do
Fi m
S w nl a
i t z nd
W N e er l a
ei th nd
gh er
te la
C z d a nds
e c ve
h r ag
Re e
pu
bl
Un B el i c
i t e giu
d m
St
a
De tes
nm
Ar
ith
a
m Au r k
et
ic s tr
av i a
er
ag
Ic e
el
an
Fr d
an
ce
Sp
ai
n
It a
Ca ly
n
Hu ad a
ng
a
Sl
ov No r y
ak r w
Re ay
pu
bl
ic
Ko
Au re a
st
ra
M li a
ex
ic
o
-50
Note: Tax rates constitute all excise taxes levied on petrol as at 01.01.2000 and 01.01.2010. Rates for the United States and Canada include
rates at the sub-central level. The weighted average is weighted by revenues from petrol taxes.
Source: OECD/EEA database on instruments for environmental policy.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317274
Motor vehicles
Along with motor fuels, taxes on motor vehicles are a major source of revenue for
OECD governments. These taxes are generally divided into two categories: those that are
one-off (that is, levied on the initial or subsequent sale or import into the country) and
those that are recurrent (that is, those that are levied on an annual basis). While
theoretically less efficient than taxes on fuel or actual emissions from an environmental
point of view, these taxes can nevertheless play a large role in affecting levels of car
ownership and the composition of a national fleet of vehicles. In addition, such taxes,
particularly those of the one-off kind, can provide a “sticker shock” effect regarding the
environmental impact that other taxes may not, as seen in Figure 2.7.
40
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
2.
CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
Figure 2.7. One-off motor vehicle taxes
Small vehicle
Medium vehicle
Large vehicle
EUR (000s)
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
nd
la
er
it z
ly
ce
an
Sw
Fr
It a
n
pa
Ja
na
Ca
at
St
d
da
es
ia
en
i te
Un
Sl
ov
li a
ra
ai
a
n
st
Au
Sp
re
Ko
nd
d
ria
st
Au
la
Ir e
an
d
nl
Fi
an
el
l
y
Ic
ke
Tu
r
ga
s
nd
r tu
Po
er
la
ar
th
nm
Ne
De
No
rw
ay
k
0
Notes: As at 01.01.2010. One-off taxes on new vehicles only. “Small” refers to a petrol-based car with 53 kW of power, 6.5 l/100 km, 821 kg,
1 000 cc engine, EUR 12 000 pre-tax price; “medium” refers to a petrol-based car with 132 kW of power, 9.4 l/100 km, 1 468 kg, 2 400 cc engine,
EUR 25 000 pre-tax price; “large” refers to a petrol-based car/SUV with 300 kW of power, 16.8 l/100 km, 2 587 kg, 6 200 cc engine,
EUR 45 000 pre-tax price. Countries with CO2 components in their taxes on motor vehicles are calculated based on fuel efficiency. For countries
with sub-national governments that levy applicable rates, the following jurisdictions are used: New South Wales (Australia), Ontario (Canada),
and California (United States). These tax levels do not include non-environmentally related taxes, such as VAT, nor environmentally related tax
components that vary significantly between vehicles of a similar size, such as those based on NOx emissions from each vehicle.
Source: OECD/EEA database on instruments for environmental policy.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317293
The manner in which such motor vehicle taxes are being administered has been
changing. OECD countries are evermore basing such charges on the characteristics of
the vehicle with environmental features being prominently utilised – fuel efficiency,
CO2 emissions per kilometre, engine power, and weight.4 In a number of cases, more than
one of these factors is used to derive a total tax burden per vehicle. This is the case in
Norway, where CO2 emissions, vehicle weight, and engine power are all used to determine
the tax level. Coupled with high tax rates for each item, the result is that Norway has
substantially higher one-off tax levels on large vehicles than most elsewhere in the OECD,
while Denmark has higher taxes for small and medium-sized vehicles, as seen in
Figure 2.7. In some cases, the tax burden, especially for larger and more polluting cars, can
represent several hundred per cent of the net-of-tax price of the vehicle.
The construction of some of these taxes exacts a significant toll on heavily emitting
vehicles. Many countries’ taxes involve formulae with many different variables. Figure 2.8
shows only the component of the tax burden (or subsidy level in some cases) on vehicles
related to their CO 2 emissions (or fuel efficiency) in OECD countries. OECD (2009b)
demonstrates that these taxes can be highly progressive with increasing emission rates,
such as in Norway and Portugal. In addition, four countries’ CO2-based component – Austria,
Finland, Ireland, and Spain – is dependent on the pre-tax price of the vehicle and in several
countries, the tax rates differ between petrol- and diesel-driven vehicles.
Figure 2.9 translates these tax levels solely from the CO 2 component into an
equivalent value per tonne of CO2 emitted over the lifetime of the vehicles, assuming that
each vehicle is driven 200 000 km. A uniform rate per tonne of CO2 would provide a
constant tax on emissions, consistent with the damage done to the environment. Fuel
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010
41
2. CURRENT USE OF ENVIRONMENTALLY RELATED TAXATION
Figure 2.8. CO2 component of one-off taxes
Petrol-driven motor vehicles, 2010
Austria
Belgium (Wallonia)
Denmark
Netherlands
Canada
Finland
France
Norway
Portugal
Ireland
Spain
United States
EUR per vehicle
70 000
EUR per vehicle
8 000
60 000
6 000
50 000
4 000
40 000
30 000
2 000
20 000
0
10 000
-2 000
0
-4 000
-10 000
-20 000
-6 000
1
1
71 101 131 161 191 221 251 281 311 341 371 400
Gram CO 2 emitted per kilometre driven
71 101 131 161 191 221 251 281 311 341 371 400
Gram CO 2 emitted per kilometre driven
Notes: The CO2 tax components for Spain, Ireland, Finland and Austria are also dependent on the pre-tax price of the vehicle; for this
exercise, a EUR 10 000 vehicle has been used. Note that the axes of the two panels are of a different scale.
Source: Updated data based on OECD (2009b).
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317312
Figure 2.9. Implicit carbon price and motor vehicle taxes
Derived solely from CO2 component of one-off, petrol-driven motor vehicle taxes
Austria
Denmark
France
Norway
EUR per tonne CO 2 emitted during the vehicle’s lifetime
1 000
Finland
Spain
Portugal
Belgium (Wallonia)
Canada
Netherlands
United States
Ireland
EUR per tonne CO 2 emitted during the vehicle’s lifetime
150
800
100
600
50
400
200
0
0
-50
-200
-150
-400
-600
-100
51
81
111 141 171 201 231 261 291 321 351 381
Gram CO 2 emitted per kilometre driven
51
81
111 141 171 201 231 261 291 321 351 381
Gram CO 2 emitted per kilometre driven
Notes: The CO2 tax components for Spain, Ireland, Finland and Austria are also dependent on the pre-tax price of the vehicle; for this exercise,
a EUR 10 000 vehicle has been used. Vehicle lifetime is assumed to be 200 000 km. Note that the axes of the two panels are of a different scale.
Source: Updated information based on OECD (2009b).
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932317331
42
TAXATION, INNOVATION AND THE ENVIRONMENT © OECD 2010